Contents

Description of CHPV and GV

Introduction
Analogy
Weightings
Voting
Counting
Outcomes
Party-List
Summary

Evaluations of CHPV and GV

Ranked Ballot

Introduction (RB)
General Criteria
Majority Criteria
Clones & Teaming
Teaming Thresholds
Summary (RB)

Party-List

Introduction (PL)
Diagrams & Maps
CHPV Maps
Optimality
Party Cloning
Proportionality
Summary (PL)

Comparisons of CHPV with other voting systems

Single-Winner

Introduction (SW)
Plurality (FPTP)
Borda Count
Geometric Voting
Positional Voting
Condorcet Methods
AV (IRV)
Plur. Rule Methods
Summary (SW)

Multiple-Winner

Introduction (MW)
STV
Party-List
PL ~ Hare
PL ~ Droop
~ Maps Opt PC Pro
PL ~ D'Hondt
~ Maps Opt PC Pro
PL ~ Sainte-Laguë
~ Maps Opt PC Pro
Mixed Member Sys
Summary (MW)

Conclusions

Ranked Ballot CHPV
Party-List CHPV

General

Table of Contents

Map Construction

Table of Contents

Mathematical Proofs

Table of Contents
Notation & Formats

Valid XHTML 1.0 Strict

Valid CSS

Home About Description Evaluations(RB) Evaluations(PL) Comparisons(SW) Comparisons(MW) Conclusions General Maps Proofs
Home About Description Evaluations(RB) Evaluations(PL) Comparisons(SW) Comparisons(MW) Conclusions General Maps Proofs
Home > Comparisons > Sainte-Laguë > Maps > Page 1 of 3
Last Revision: New on 25 Aug 2012

Comparisons: Sainte-Laguë ~ Maps 1

Two-Party Sainte-Laguë Party-List Maps

Two-party maps contain all the possible election outcomes for a given number of winners in a two-party election. The maps for two parties A and B contesting up to six vacancies in closed Sainte-Laguë Party-List elections are shown below. Recall that the actual per-unit tally shares for A and B are represented by the appropriate point along the line. The domain boundaries of an optimally proportional voting (OPV) system are indicated by the dotted markers underneath the line. These optimal boundaries are necessarily midway between the dots that represent perfect proportionality between the outcome seat share ratio (as stated underneath the dot) and the tally share ratio (point on the line) as defined by the voters.

The boundaries for the Sainte-Laguë domains are determined by the various two-way critical ties that may occur in elections with W winners. For the specific details of how party stick diagrams are used to deduce the position of these boundaries, please refer to the Map Construction appendix for the Two-Party Sainte-Laguë Method Maps page.

Sainte-Laguë Method two-party single-winner Map Sainte-Laguë Method two-party two-winner Map Sainte-Laguë Method two-party three-winner Map Sainte-Laguë Method two-party four-winner Map Sainte-Laguë Method two-party five-winner Map Sainte-Laguë Method two-party six-winner Map

At least for two parties, it is clear from the above maps that the Sainte-Laguë method is an optimally proportional voting (OPV) system. Let the length of an inner domain be one unit. The length of each end domain is therefore a half-unit. Starting at either end, the domain boundaries occur at intervals of 1/2, 3/2, 5/2 units and so on from that end. Notice that the numerator sequence is 1, 3, 5 and so on. It is no co-incidence that these numbers are also the divisors used in the Sainte-Laguë method. In fact, this sequence of divisors was deliberately chosen so that optimum proportionality would inherently be achieved. It makes no difference how many seats are available, the outcome is always optimal for two competing parties.


Proceed to next page > Comparisons: Sainte-Laguë ~ Maps 2

Return to previous page > Comparisons: Party-List ~ Sainte-Laguë