Contents

Description of CHPV and GV

Introduction
Analogy
Weightings
Voting
Counting
Outcomes
Party-List
Summary

Evaluations of CHPV and GV

Ranked Ballot

Introduction (RB)
General Criteria
Majority Criteria
Clones & Teaming
Teaming Thresholds
Summary (RB)

Party-List

Introduction (PL)
Diagrams & Maps
CHPV Maps
Optimality
Party Cloning
Proportionality
Summary (PL)

Comparisons of CHPV with other voting systems

Single-Winner

Introduction (SW)
Plurality (FPTP)
Borda Count
Geometric Voting
Positional Voting
Condorcet Methods
AV (IRV)
Plur. Rule Methods
Summary (SW)

Multiple-Winner

Introduction (MW)
STV
Party-List
PL ~ Hare
PL ~ Droop
~ Maps Opt PC Pro
PL ~ D'Hondt
~ Maps Opt PC Pro
PL ~ Sainte-Laguë
~ Maps Opt PC Pro
Mixed Member Sys
Summary (MW)

Conclusions

Ranked Ballot CHPV
Party-List CHPV

General

Table of Contents

Map Construction

Table of Contents

Mathematical Proofs

Table of Contents
Notation & Formats

Valid XHTML 1.0 Strict

Valid CSS

Home About Description Evaluations(RB) Evaluations(PL) Comparisons(SW) Comparisons(MW) Conclusions General Maps Proofs
Home About Description Evaluations(RB) Evaluations(PL) Comparisons(SW) Comparisons(MW) Conclusions General Maps Proofs
Home > Proofs > Positional Voting > CV6
Last Revision: 25 May 2020

Mathematical Proofs: Positional Voting

Proof CV6: Consensus and Polarization Indices for Truncated GV(r) Vectors

The standard positional voting vector for geometric voting with a common ratio of r is given below.

Proof CV6a

This vector following truncation of its last preference from wN = rN-1 to wN = 0 is shown below.

Proof CV6b

The formula for calculating each bias index is given in the Consensus and Polarization Indices for Positional Voting Vectors proof. It is however useful to determine the sum of all the preference weightings first. Geometric voting derives its name from the fact that its preference weightings form a geometric progression. As such, the standard mathematical formula for determining the sum of the first N-1 terms in a geometric progression is used here. Note that the Nth term is zero.

Proof CV6c

Notice that the sum Σ is a function of both the common ratio r and the number of candidates N. Hence, the two bias indices are also functions of these variables; see below

Proof CV6d

The table below gives the Consensus Index (CIV) value for the truncated GV(r) vector for selected values of r up to ten candidates. The corresponding table for the untruncated version is given in proof CV2.

Consensus Index Table for Truncated GV Vectors

As the number of candidates tends to infinity (N → ∞), the sum Σ simply reduces to 1/(1-r). Therefore, the two bias indices can be greatly simplified here as shown below.

Proof CV6e

As the number of candidates (N) increases, the Consensus Index (CIV) for a truncated GV(r) vector - like that for the untruncated vector - converges towards its asymptote. However, for N > 2 and r > 0, this index is consistently closer to its asymptotic value of r with the truncated vector (TV) rather than the untruncated vector (UV). The table below gives the difference in consensus index values (CITV - CIUV) between the two.

Consensus Index Difference Table for GV Vectors

Notice that the non-zero values in the above table are all positive. This demonstrates that the untruncated vector never has a consensus index closer to its asymptotic value (r) than the truncated version. In a large field of candidates (especially when N → ∞) the difference in these two indices is minimal. If however, it is desired for the system bias to remain close to CIV = r in a relatively small field of candidates, then the truncation of any GV(r) vector such that wN = 0 will significantly advance this objective.

Therefore, when designing a positional voting system to exhibit a specific bias without prior knowledge of the number of candidates that will be nominated, this is essentially achieved by selecting the appropriate common ratio for the vector such that r = CIV = 1 - PIV and truncating its last preference weighting to wN = 0.


Return to main text > Comparisons: Positional Voting 10

Refer to > Mathematical Proofs: Table of Contents